5 Pliable Citizenship Migrant Inequality in the Xi Jinping Era
Alexsia T. Chan
The municipal government in Shanghai rolled out reforms in the late 2000s and early 2010s that allowed migrant children to attend primary school in the city regardless of their household registration status. However, staff at a community organization that supported migrant education told me in 2012 that migrant workers faced systematic obstacles when they tried to enroll their children in public school. Officials explained that meaningful progress would take time and that any issues they had been encountering were temporary hiccups. Five years later, workers at the same organization reported in follow-up interviews that many migrants were mired between supposedly having rights and actually obtaining access. The case was much the same in other cities.1
Important political changes had happened in the intervening years. Xi Jinping ascended to the top position in government and consolidated power, prompting questions about the degree of his influence. In 2014, the State Council unveiled the innovative National New-Type Urbanization Plan (2014–20).2 The multipronged plan promised “human-centered” urbanization, marking a contrast with previous rapid economic development and committing to help those who were most marginalized. One major aim of the plan was economic. Urbanization, as it has elsewhere in the world, would lead to more economic development, higher wages for workers, and a growing middle class who could drive domestic consumption. The State Council announced, “An increasing urbanization ratio will help raise the income of rural residents through employment in cities and unleash the consumption potential, according to the plan.”3 Another key dimension was building the infrastructural and human capital support necessary to back this economic goal: “It will also bring about large demands for investment in urban infrastructure, public service facilities, and housing construction, thus providing continuous impetus for economic development.”4 The plan seemed to usher in a period of concern for the well-being of migrant workers as part of larger state goals. But the contrast between the lived experience on the ground and high-level directives suggests that less has changed than the plan promised. Municipalities still have to translate the plan’s ambitious goals into social insurance plans, hospital agreements, accessible schools, classroom spots, affordable housing, transferrable pensions, and more.
Why has urban public service provision for migrant workers remained uneven and devolved to local governments? This situation is especially puzzling given that it has continued at the same time that Xi Jinping has centralized authority in many other policy areas, both domestic and foreign. His administration has ushered in an anti-corruption campaign, Belt and Road Initiative projects, and a greater commitment to improving the quality of life of Chinese citizens. But while he has poured resources into the first two, the last remains left to local governments to address through formulating and implementing policies for outsiders living and working in their cities.
Public service provision for migrants remains patchy and devolved to local government control because inequality serves the state. There has been more continuity than change between administrations in this particular governance issue. Local authorities enact social control through the contingent delivery of social services, and these practices have continued apace under Xi because they work well enough to support other state goals, namely, economic development and social stability. It allows the central government to claim commitments to increasing equality, while municipal governments can maintain a labor force for whom they do not have to provide the full set of services. However, decentralized benefits are not designed to improve the overall welfare of a group of people defined by their movement and mobility.
Municipal and district authorities use what I call “pliable citizenship,” a term that reflects an outsider’s social rights to the city that are dependent on place, time, and the individual migrant.5 That is, a migrant’s ability to access and use services in the city can change based on the policies and practices implemented in the city or district where the migrant happens to be working and living that year.6 The moldability of eligibility requirements, obstacles to access, and hoop-jumping give local bureaucrats and frontline service providers some flexibility in choosing to whom they provide health care, education, housing, and other entitlements. Pliable citizenship is a component of a larger process of the “political atomization” of Chinese migrants.7
Despite the central government’s renewed attention to the consequences of urbanization, less has changed for the people on the ground than anticipated. This finding that continuity trumps change runs counter to the notion of a universal and sweeping “Xi Jinping effect.” In problematizing evaluations of Xi’s influence, this chapter highlights what has largely not changed and why. Marginal shifts have occurred, but many of these were set in motion during the prior administration. The provision of social entitlements continues to be the responsibility of local authorities; however, people who move around the country would benefit more from a centralized system that allows transfers between cities and counties. The Xi Jinping effect on migrant inequality has been limited so far.
The Long-Standing Urbanization Challenge
The need to manage economic development, the flow of workers, and the attendant growth of cities has been a policy issue since the early 1980s. Four decades ago, rural surplus labor moved to urban centers to fuel production for the export market. Urban bias has helped induce internal migration in China, and workers continue to move today.8 After migrants arrive and settle down, they require access to public services such as health care, housing, and education for their children. The core challenge for local governments is to maintain a steady and healthy labor force, but they are reluctant to bear the burden of fully incorporating migrant workers into the urban public welfare system. Demographic trends, structural shifts in the economy, and other changes in the past decade have reshaped the practical demands facing municipal and district officials. One aspect that has stayed consistent is statist attempts to control, manage, and channel internal migrants in order to maintain steady economic growth and social stability. It is a thorny problem that cannot be shoved aside because, ultimately, cities need workers.
Previous literature on Chinese migrant workers focuses heavily on the household registration (hukou) system and their second-class citizenship. The hukou system has long relegated internal migrants to a social underclass.9 It dictated registered rural residents’ rights to benefits in their urban destinations for several decades and tied them to their hometown or (for the second generation of migrants) their parents’ hometowns. Many in the “floating population” (liudong renkou) at that point did not settle long-term into cities. The expectation that they would return to their village in the countryside for medical care or their children’s schooling was problematic and inconvenient but was the norm. The demographics and the lifetime plans of migrants have changed. More are older, are married, have children, and would prefer to settle down permanently in their chosen destinations.10 These trends have made it more difficult, costly, and unrealistic over time to expect migrants to live and work in one place and obtain social services elsewhere in the country.
The hukou system has evolved over the years and undergone changes. Recent reforms have led to “localization” of the system and related policies and procedures rather than abolishment.11 Although it continues to exist as a national system, the entitlements that come with registration vary by place. Cities are developing their own schemes for determining who can register and through what procedures. For example, the country’s capital has established its own eligibility criteria for acquiring a Beijing hukou.12 At the same time, with the devolution of authority the household registration system is not necessarily the main or only determinant of migrants’ social rights on the ground.
In contrast to the bright-line distinction between rural migrants and urban residents that once existed because of the hukou system, gradations in second-class citizenship among migrant workers have emerged.13 Differentiation among migrant workers themselves has become politically salient. Highly educated migrants from other cities are typically more desirable than low-skilled workers who have moved from the countryside. A lawyer who has relocated to Shanghai from another city has an easier time accessing health care and education opportunities for his or her children than a nanny does who is originally from a village in Henan Province. Employment status, industry, residency period, and other factors further differentiate one migrant worker from the next in terms of urban citizenship. New gradations in second-class status are more complex, varied, and contingent.
These degrees of second-class citizenship emerged before Xi came to power. Policies, procedures, and practices are cementing them into institutions in cities, and they continue to evolve as municipal authorities’ needs and preferences change. They are a direct consequence of the localization of migrant social rights in lieu of the abolishment of the hukou system or a national overhaul of it. In other words, they do not fit into the broader pattern of centralization of power and consolidation of authoritarianism that has characterized the Xi era so far.14 They largely originated under Hu Jintao and have continued under Xi. Why they have persisted is part of the Xi legacy, but for reasons other than his consolidation of power.
Structural features of policy implementation affect public goods provision for migrants on the ground. Local officials are subject to the cadre evaluation system, and “street-level bureaucrats” engage in decentralized decision-making.15 Both result in uneven public service provision for migrants. The cadre evaluation system with its mix of performance metrics and incentives shapes selective policy implementation and leaves room for discretion at the local level.16 The decentralized implementation of services, to be clear, helps explain why there is variation in practice but not necessarily what forms that variation takes to aid social control and entrench migrant inequality. Although central leadership policies on migrant public services may change, the cadre management system and local politics and structures remain intact.
There are a number of alternative explanations for why various local governments treat migrant workers differently. The simplest reason could be wealth: richer cities can afford to spend more on public services for outsiders. But wealth does not explain why when making education accessible to migrant students, Beijing is generally exclusionary, Shanghai has had limited success, and Chengdu is doing especially well. Nor does it explain variation over time within these cities or differences between regional cities such as Dongguan and Hangzhou. Wealthier cities should be better equipped to manage an unfunded mandate, but they have other competing policy priorities, which are similar to the constraints leading cadres face within the cadre responsibility system.17 In addition, local officials and urban residents are sometimes reluctant to share resources with rural migrants, whom some see as outsiders and troublemakers. A few megacities are seeking to cap their populations in the coming years and thus are unlikely to do anything that would lure more people, such as by expanding benefits.
Labor shortages are another alternative explanation for why some cities and not others treat migrants better. Cities in the Pearl River delta in Guangdong Province have experienced labor shortages since about 2004, but improvement in services has been more recent and dependent on limited local hukou reform.18 The mechanism seems plausible, but municipalities and companies often use other ways to draw in workers when they are needed. Low-skilled labor shortages do not usually lead to changes in social service provision. Moreover, the relationship may be the reverse: the hukou system (and associated restrictions on benefits for workers who have relocated) may contribute to labor shortages.19 According to the small and medium-size factory owners in Guangdong and Sichuan Provinces whom I interviewed, only the largest factories, with tens or hundreds of thousands of workers, have enough economic and political sway to try to influence local, never mind national, policy. They explained that only when a company can offer as many new jobs as a large multinational company will the local government respond directly to a particular labor shortage.20 In those cases, the local government may offer to bus in laborers from nearby villages or provide support such as worker training.21 Furthermore, the 2008 global economic turndown affected firms across the country, but not all cities have improved services in response. Meanwhile, workers are flocking inland, where services had already been improving. Social policy is not the main quick fix for metropolitan areas trying to resolve labor shortages.
Recent developments indicate that migrant workers may be gaining more leverage and therefore should be better positioned to demand more social protection. To be sure, some aspects of migrants’ quality of life are improving and they are enjoying higher wages. Labor shortages also tip the power imbalance more toward workers, but they continue to face high institutional barriers. Meanwhile, labor unrest is on the rise. According to the China Labour Bulletin, data show that reported strikes (likely only a small fraction of total strikes in a given year) increased from 184 in 2011 to 1,257 in 2017.22 In the first eight months of 2018 alone, 1,134 strikes had been logged on the organization’s strike map.23 In 2014, as many as forty thousand workers at the Yue Yuen shoe factory complex in Dongguan, Guangdong, in “the world’s factory” in southeastern China, went on strike for two weeks. They protested what they claim had been years of inadequate social insurance and housing fund contributions the company should have paid. Yue Yuen facilities produced shoes for global brands, including Adidas, Nike, and Saucony. Although social benefits are not the most common reason workers strike, this strike was one of the largest in recent memory, according to labor activists. A Guangzhou labor dispute litigation white paper stated that unpaid social insurance accounted for more than 40 percent of arbitration cases from 2014 to 2016.24 Some workers are beginning to seek redress for benefits owed, but the scope of their requests is often limited to the companies not paying, rather than placing the onus on the state. Labor unrest has also become more offensive, suggesting there are at least perceived openings in political opportunity.25 Workers have demanded repayment of wage arears, better working conditions, and more. For migrants, increased leverage and assertiveness have not yet directly resulted in systematic reform of urban social services.
Many observers have assumed that the second generation of migrant workers could and would push for a stronger social safety net. Second-generation migrants are the children of the migrant workers who participated in the initial massive wave of rural-to-urban migration in the 1980s. Many were born and raised in the city, but their household registration record is still tied to their parents’ and they retain their rural registration status. Some experience more anger and dissatisfaction than the first generation, and most are more highly educated than their parents.26 That second-generation migrants are younger than first-generation migrants also means that they are healthier and less likely to have children.27 From construction workers to factory line workers, they are more concerned about quality of life (for example, working fewer hours or in less potentially toxic job environments) than public education or health care.28 Though individual companies may face different demands depending on the type of worker most suitable for their business, the overall cohort breakdown by first- and second-generation migrants in a city does not affect broader government policies. Where migrants have banded together to access social services in the city, it was to circumvent rules of exclusion from government-sponsored schemes or to form informal institutions to serve as private alternatives. Differences between cities in the proportion of first- and second-generation migrants do not appear to influence how the state treats migrants overall. The benefits of keeping citizenship pliable and other overriding state goals better explain public service provision for migrant workers.
Problematizing the Xi Effect
National directives toward supporting urbanization as economic development notwithstanding, there has been more continuity than change under Xi Jinping, as local authorities’ use of pliable citizenship continues to shape migrant workers’ benefits. The policies and practices set in motion during the Hu Jintao administration serve the central government’s broader goals of economic development and social stability, and this form of inequality has been maintained under the current administration.
Top-Down View: Urbanization as Development
Urbanization is state led and state supported in China. The process of urbanizing people (and land) is seen as a means to further economic development and modernization. Central pronouncements declare a more balanced approach to urbanization that would alleviate some of the past problems and address inequity. The attention has matched other campaigns to reduce socioeconomic disparity, but concrete measures have lagged behind the words. Discussions of inequality in China often converge on two points: remarkable progress in poverty alleviation and the ever stubborn rural-urban divide.29 Migrants, however, have not yet become fully integrated into their urban destinations. Verbal overtures about incorporating outsiders are a start, but they are not enough to improve migrant welfare without a national overhaul.
The focus on urbanization as development came from among the topmost powers in Beijing. Li Keqiang fixated on urbanization during his post as premier under Xi Jinping and made urbanization a central component of economic reform. According to Li, urbanization was the key to unlocking China’s domestic consumption and subsequently improving people’s welfare. His focus on urbanization and economic development was visible and widely touted when Xi first rose to power. In a 2012 article expounding his views on the urbanization drive, Li said, “Stepping up efforts to abolish the ‘two-tier class system’ will help rebalance urban-rural development, resolve social conflicts and unleash the untapped potential for domestic demand which will result from urbanization.”30 He drew a clear line from reducing inequality between registered urban residents and migrants to untapping rural labor and unleashing latent domestic demand. The process of urbanization itself would boost the economy as well as create the basis of future market growth by making more people city residents, who would then become urban consumers.
Li also made the link between public service provision for migrants and the urbanization process. In the same article, he pointed to the need for government responsibility in helping to provide migrant workers with health care, education, and more: “The government should formulate and ensure the seamless implementation of policies and measures which encourage migrant workers to integrate into cities, while also ensuring that they are covered by, and have equal access to basic public services, including urban social security, health care, education and culture. The government should help them solve problems concerning employment, housing, health care and children’s education.”31 The article, however, did not specify the role of the central and local governments in formulating and implementing policies that would actually make migrant workers full-fledged citizens. Nor, for example, did it lay out a financial restructuring plan to increase transfers to municipal governments so they could pay for expanding their public goods systems. And it did not provide details on where new schools and hospitals for migrants and their children would be built, how these organizations would hire appropriate teachers and doctors to staff them, how migrants would be able to navigate any new eligibility and access requirements set by bureaucracies, and other logistics behind any meaningful incorporation.
The notion of urbanization as development seems to have fallen out of the national spotlight. While it is difficult to discern whether what publicly appeared to be a slow fade was the product of a completed policy goal or explicit reprioritization, it has diminished in relative rhetorical importance to other policy initiatives. At a speech seven years later, at the 2019 Summer Davos meeting, Li still emphasized the idea of putting people at the center of development priorities. But there was less weight placed on urbanization and incorporating migrants. He made broad mentions of improving people’s well-being overall, saying, “The Chinese government will continue to put people first in pursuing development, explore innovative means to enhance people’s well-being, and provide more quality public goods and services to better share the fruits of reform and development among our people.”32 Other economic priorities have taken center stage as the Chinese government fears a substantial slowdown in growth. That has left migrants empty-handed in terms of the significant integration that had been promoted at the start of the Xi era.
Li Keqiang was not the only vocal supporter of urbanization and improving migrant workers’ welfare. A number of central proclamations and directives have shown rhetorical support for improving migrants’ and their dependents’ access to primary education, use of social insurance in the city, affordable housing, and pensions. The National New-Type Urbanization Plan (2014–20) suggests a longer commitment to ensuring that people moving from the countryside to the city would enjoy more services. The plan included the goal of converting one hundred million more rural residents’ hukou into urban registrations and improving access to hospitals and schools for those already living in urban areas.33 China’s drive for urbanization is synonymous with modernization because advanced, industrialized countries are urbanized. According to the plan, different forms of migrant inequality, from public services to land rights, would be addressed as part of this process.
The Chinese Dream is another example of central concern and signaling. The amorphous and wide-reaching slogan carries grand notions of national rejuvenation but offers little in the way of specifics. Part of it seeks to address the effects of uneven development during the economic reform period. In a report to the 19th National Congress of the Communist Party of China in the Great Hall of the People in Beijing in 2017, Xi said, “What we now face is the contradiction between unbalanced and inadequate development and the people’s ever-growing needs for a better life.”34 An optimistic interpretation would include in this group of people China’s hundreds of millions of internal migrants. Projects focused on specific aspects of quality of life, such as the “Common Prosperity” campaign and Healthy China 2030, add more hope.35 (See Martin King Whyte’s chapter in this volume for more on inequality under Xi.) Taken together, such directives show that the Xi government appears invested in devoting attention to this large group of marginalized people in China, at least according to these announcements and plans.
Other national projects seek to direct the pace and location of urbanization. While urbanization would continue even without state intervention because China is a developing country, the Xi government is intent on speeding it up. The aim is to control the geographic concentration of movement, mostly to small and medium-size cities and to a lesser extent to urban mega-regions outside metropolises’ existing central business districts. The state is devoted to leading and supporting the urbanization process insofar that it takes a certain form. A government publication called the “Key Tasks of New-Type Urbanization Construction in 2019” recommends that cities with a permanent population between one and three million people should lift residency requirements that prevent migrant workers from accessing urban social services.36 These small and medium cities usually cannot offer the economic opportunity and co-migrant networks that are available in coastal cities, which have long been popular destinations for the “floating population.” A mismatch between central state goals, local authorities’ priorities and constraints, and migrant preferences ends up undermining the overarching idealistic project of deepening urbanization in a less than organic way. Li Keqiang, too, described his own plan for migrant incorporation: “Qualification requirements should be relaxed for those rural migrant workers with stable jobs and housing to become permanent urban residents of mid-sized and small cities.”37 These qualifications concerning employment stability, housing permanence, and residency status are subtle and build on a number of policies and practices that had been in place before a Xi effect could have begun.
More Continuity than Change: Pliable Citizenship in Practice
One way to evaluate the Xi Jinping effect is to assess the degree of continuity and change between administrations. It can help establish whether there is a distinct shift from changing paramount leaders and, if so, its extent. To be clear, continuity or little change does not necessarily mean that the later leader is ineffectual or that this leader is not minding the issue. If policies are sufficient or functioning, then the leader may choose to maintain them as they are. That too is a decision, though one that is less discernibly the effect of an individual. Intent, as is often the case, is difficult to measure but need not be considered to observe the outcomes of migrant inequality. This chapter focuses on the perspective on the ground of migrant workers engaged in navigating municipal and district rules on social services and the local officials and street-level service providers responsible for these public goods. Both the Hu and Xi administrations’ central directives included inclusive and expansionary rhetoric. A closer look at how they are translated into municipal policies shows that city newcomers’ access to public goods is actually highly differentiated and becoming more so.
The devolution of authority and responsibility for migrants’ integration into cities is a major source of inequality. The central directives mentioned notwithstanding, the formulation and the implementation of specific policies to bring outsiders into the local urban public health, education, housing, and pension systems fall to municipalities. Local officials are responsible for designing schemes that dictate who does and does not qualify for benefits. For those who do qualify, they must then ensure that they have adequate access and can actually use the entitlements given to them. Officials therefore exercise discretion and devise systems such as points schemes to determine eligibility for permanent residency status. These complicated systems award points to applicants for qualifications such as having a university degree. They make it appear as if inclusion is possible and procedures do exist, but they continue to exclude most migrants. Beijing, for example, granted hukou only to 6,019 people who had the most points out of 124,000 applicants.38 Few gain full citizenship.
Many city officials feel hamstrung because of crosscutting pressures. The combination of central concern and local responsibility often leads to an unfunded mandate, referred to by Chinese as “The center treats, local governments pay” (Zhongyang qingke, dangdi maidan).39 Because migrants are managed locally and support from above is minimal, cities get to choose whom to incorporate and on what terms. Fully incorporating migrants would require significant resources. The Chinese Academy of Social Sciences estimated it would cost approximately ¥650 billion (or US$106 billion) a year to ensure that rural migrants have the same health care, education, and housing benefits that their urban resident counterparts have.40 But cities cannot forego the labor of migrants. They also need them to support the local economy by ferrying takeout lunch orders to the business crowd, cleaning major city streets, building new residential construction, and more. And principals and hospital administrators must respond when migrants show up in their schools and health-care facilities looking to enroll their children or use their social insurance to receive medical treatment.
Decentralization leaves room for local governments to enact pliable citizenship. Pliable citizenship involves migrant workers’ social rights being dependent on place, time, and characteristics of the individual. Their ability to qualify for, access, and use urban social services can vary based on where they live and work and their hometown or province. Being qualified does not guarantee access or use either. One year they may have a harder time enrolling their children in the local public school than the next year. They may also have more entitlements if they moved from another city instead of a village, have a formal job with a signed labor contract, work at a state-owned enterprise, or can prove long-term residency with a lease or by buying a house. One migrant’s actualized citizenship may differ from another outsider’s, which is a different contrast than that between a native urban resident and a registered rural counterpart. While urban authorities do have some leeway and could potentially open up their cities more, they face other pragmatic constraints.
Urban authorities, therefore, sometimes provide “phantom services” in lieu of full incorporation.41 Many municipalities deflect demands for benefits instead of meeting them or denying them outright. City leaders often establish near-impossible eligibility requirements and require paperwork that outsiders struggle to obtain. Municipal authorities also nudge migrants to seek health care or education elsewhere by enforcing dormant rules, shutting down schools and clinics, and encouraging migrants to seek out cheaper options in another city or in the countryside. Urban officials deflect migrants for practical and political reasons. Limiting access is both cost-effective and done in a way that isolates and disempowers migrants and makes it harder for them to protest collectively. Phantom services change the locus of contention, aid “social management” (shehui guanli), and expose new axes of inequality.
Pliable citizenship predates the Xi era. Several years before he came to power, for example, Shanghai announced it would provide free education to all school-age migrant children. The outcome has been mixed, but the action of making the formal statement itself is noteworthy. Other cities are developing their own sets of policies and rules around public education and other types of benefits. More systematic national overhauls seem to be far off. Claims that incremental changes will eventually amount to full integration into cities are unsubstantiated so far. Xi has not recentralized fiscal responsibility and policymaking in this realm, and he has not done much to advance the incorporation of rural migrants in cities. Any changes since 2012 have happened at the edges. It would be difficult to describe this as incremental progress because the steps taken do not appear to build on each other toward a larger goal of dismantling the institutions behind migrant inequity.
The patchwork of local policies works because of the lack of centralized coordination, not in spite of it. Decentralization in migrant benefits persists beyond the Hu administration because it continues to be in Beijing’s interest. The state benefits whether it was intentionally designed this way from the top or not and regardless of whether China has the state capacity to completely overhaul the public goods system. Given the consolidation of power that follows other central policy goals, the combination of verbal commitments from the top but without resources and details to support them suggests that the current system works as is.
Devolved responsibility started before Xi, but his government has done little to advance the full incorporation of migrants. Xi’s authority and efficacy are not necessarily less relevant or potent. Rather, officials have allowed an effective system (or, more accurately, a set of multiple subnational systems) to continue functioning while it is good enough. That a leader would allow a system to keep plodding along does not necessarily imply that decisions were not made about the processes in place. Insofar as this system of labor pool management suiting broader policy goals, this is unsurprising. It becomes more relevant as the Chinese economy undergoes structural adjustments, which should lead to necessary industrial upgrading but which will nonetheless involve some growing pains as the growth rate slows from the height of approximately 10 percent. But that system does not work toward primarily improving migrant welfare.
Retrenchment and reversal are underway in some places. A few of the largest cities are attempting to cap the number of people living in those metropolitan areas and are seeking to disincentivize further population growth. The Beijing Municipal Master Plan (2016–35), officially approved by the Party Central Committee and the State Council, set a goal of capping the city’s population at twenty-three million by 2020.42 Shanghai followed, with a cap of twenty-five million people by 2035. These goals seem incompatible to many given the existing population in both cities, with vulnerable migrants likely to bear the brunt of any population management policies to come. Migrant integration therefore remains uneven, especially as these cities and others in similar positions appear to inch away from full incorporation.
Whether hukou and public service provision reforms are gradual (as most officials say) or stalled, the effect is the same. The drawn-out process framed as incremental changes benefits the state. Pliable citizenship is a by-product of gradual reform, regardless of whether the abolishment of the household registration system or the complete integration of migrants is on the horizon. A government report compiled in 2019 by the National Health Commission’s Migrant Population Service Center, the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, the China Population and Development Research Center, and Renmin University’s Population and Research Center found that less than 4 percent of migrants in fifty cities (including Qingdao and Chengdu) were able to obtain permanent residence status in their adopted city.43 Xiao Zihua, director of the National Health Commission’s Migrant Population Service Center, said, “The larger the city, the more difficult it is for migrants to integrate.… Migrants most want to integrate into big cities and mega-cities, but our urbanization strategy is at odds with that as we encourage them to move to small and medium cities.”44 Both the numbers and this official’s statement confirm that migrants face obstacles similar to those encountered during Xi’s early administration. Most outsiders continue to run up against high institutional barriers, while a select few enjoy a slim possibility of integration. Furthermore, the mismatch between the state’s urbanization strategy and migrant workers’ preferences lingers.
Bottom-Up View: Migrant Workers’ Lived Experience
Migrants’ own point of view shows how pliable citizenship works on the ground. Their lived experience reveals the ways in which a general Xi effect is overstated on the specific issue of migrant inequality. Migrants’ responses in interviews conducted in the years before and after Xi Jinping came to power are remarkably similar. Qualitative descriptions of their attempts to qualify for, access, and use public services in coastal and inland cities indicate that pliable citizenship has been in practice since the period spanning the 2010s. They, too, heard about the urbanization drive and the central directives encouraging integration and better access to urban public goods. But they learned through their own experiences and those of their family, friends, and co-migrants as they encountered new bureaucratic roadblocks that only a selective group of migrants reaped newfound benefits. Disenchantment and a sense of powerlessness quickly followed their initial feeling of hope.
Almost all migrants describe a messy hodgepodge of various municipal and district systems. Every city has its own set of standards, so understanding the rules in one place is of little use once migrants move to another destination when following a new construction or manufacturing job lead. Or a school official tells them the school is full and instructs them to get in line for the following year.45 Within a city, each district may make its own determinations about who is worthy of which benefits. Migrant children whose parents try to enroll them in public schools in the central business district often face higher barriers than if they were in a “migrant village” on the outskirts of the city, where competition for spots in high-quality schools is less fierce.46
Many migrants report wasted time and feelings of frustration. After they figure out what “five documents” (wuzheng) they need to prove eligibility, then they go about collecting them. Typically, these include a household registration booklet, proof of hometown permanent residency, a temporary residence permit, proof of local address, and proof of employment. Not all of these certifications are easily accessible, and some might be in their hometown or do not exist at all. Those who manage to gather everything must then bring their paperwork to be certified. Here, too, migrants get stuck between supposedly being eligible and being able to prove it officially. A small shop owner working in Guangzhou said, “They ask for this certificate and that certificate: proof of housing, social insurance cards, and labor contracts. It’s almost impossible.”47 The few who are successful once may need to start all over the next year when their child graduates from primary school to middle school or if the family moves to another city or district. After trying, many give up and opt to send their children to live with their grandparents in their home village or to stay in boarding schools on the periphery just outside the city.48 Part of what makes pliable citizenship work is that it is hard for outsiders to get a bird’s-eye view of migrant inequality. Migrant workers know their own experiences and the shared stories of people in their networks. However, they are often in similar circumstances and are running into the same phantom services that never appear. Over time they learn to expect less and less from the promised incorporation they hear is coming.
Pliable citizenship also works by shifting responsibility to migrants themselves for obtaining their own services. While cities are the providers, the onus is on outsiders to prove their worthiness and follow the proper timeline to file paperwork. In addition to the formal rules, they must navigate and adhere to informal norms. Schools may require “voluntary” donations or other extra fees in order for children to secure a spot on the roster, as was the experience of a woman who left two children at home in Anhui Province while she worked as a street sweeper in Shanghai.49 Specialists in hospitals may treat some people ahead of others because these patients can afford to give them red envelopes of cash, bottles of duty-free alcohol from the airport, and other gifts, as observed during transactions at hospitals in Beijing and elsewhere. If their paperwork is insufficient, as was the case of a roadside fruit and vegetable seller who did not have a storefront lease to show proof of employment, then they are told they should have secured a more formal, permanent position. A woman from Henan Province who sold vegetables in Beijing explained that she sold one head of bok choy for five mao (US$0.07) and earned a couple of thousand kuai per month, hardly enough to buy a house in her Beijing neighborhood, which she estimated to cost 10,000 kuai (US$1,370.00) per square meter.50 The responsibility, and therefore the blame, is on individuals who have the least leverage.
The barriers are more than bureaucratic red tape. The practical consequences of pliable citizenship in forms such as phantom services and political atomization are not only annoyances. Excessive complexity may delay outcomes and result in inaction, but the key difference here is that the official procedures effectively keep out most migrants altogether. Few experience success or reward because most cannot accumulate enough points in points systems or provide the correct paperwork (for example, signed labor contracts or housing leases) to prove their periods of employment and residences. For city officials reluctant to welcome all newcomers and for frontline service providers strapped for resources, it is convenient to use procedural reasons for limiting access to public hospitals, public schools, low-income housing, and city pensions. Many migrants work six days per week for twelve hours or more per day. They do not have the luxury of time to constantly learn new rules and run around chasing paper trails, so many resign themselves to being empty-handed despite central calls for “human-centered” urbanization.
There are stories of success that circulate. Some cities that experienced influxes of migrants later than coastal areas seem more open. Chengdu, for example, certifies private migrant schools instead of shutting them down, as Beijing has done in the past.51 This serves migrants better since their children are already attending them, and the buildings tend to be located in more convenient neighborhoods. Urban public hospitals may arrange agreements that allow migrants to seek a percentage of reimbursement from their rural insurance.52 There are some stories of successfully enrolling migrant children in public schools in megacities. But when pressed, it becomes evident that it is usually a certain kind of migrant who can achieve this. Doctors, lawyers, and similarly highly educated people who have relocated from another city typically have multiple avenues of assistance. The vast majority of so-called unskilled migrant workers do not have a law school or company that can support their hukou change or their efforts to buy into urban social services. The gap between their aspirations and reality can be demoralizing. One report found that even 7.5 years after migrating to urban areas, rural Chinese migrants are on average less happy than they might have been had they not moved.53 Whispers and rumors of hope have not yet materialized into widespread, deep integration across the “floating population.”
Decentralization and pliable citizenship create uncertainty for migrant workers. Being perennially deflected and excluded makes it hard to plan work and life. Certain jobs, especially informal ones such as nannying, are precarious, and workers are reluctant to bring their children along when they move if they cannot be assured they can go to school during the day while they are at work.54 The second generation of migrant workers desire to settle down long-term in cities, and not knowing whether they can use their insurance or if they will have a pension in the city when they retire makes it hard to calculate the risks and rewards of planting roots. Difficulty accessing housing is another dimension of insecurity, as tens of thousands of migrants in Beijing experienced when they were suddenly evicted from their homes after a deadly fire in an apartment building in Daxing District in 2017. The dehumanizing bureaucratic term low-end population lays bare how the government perceives them in terms of their supposed low value-added manual labor. From this perspective, not much has changed since Xi assumed power.
Conclusion
Urbanization presents a long-standing governance challenge for the Chinese state. Higher-paying jobs and the prospect of making life better for their children entice migrants to move from rural to urban areas, and cities need these workers to sustain local economies. These outsiders eventually require access to health care, education, and other benefits in their destinations. In the Xi Jinping era of increased power consolidation, public services for migrant workers have remained devolved to municipal governments and contingent. The state’s urbanization drive is rooted in the central government’s vision of development that relies less and less on export-led growth. Pressures facing municipalities and districts and the policies they have devised in response existed before Xi came to power, and the procedures and practices behind pliable citizenship are a thread of continuity between administrations. From the perspective of city newcomers, their day-to-day experience in qualifying for, accessing, and using public hospitals, schools, housing, and pensions has not changed much. The Xi Jinping effect on migrant inequality is relatively limited because pliable citizenship and decentralization work well enough to support economic growth and social stability.
Problematizing the Xi effect shows that efficaciousness must be considered in terms of the state’s larger goals. The persistence of pliable citizenship suggests that the Xi administration’s rhetoric about migrant incorporation fits into a narrow and particular vision of urbanization. It prefers to channel this through the growth of small and medium cities, which is not necessarily in the interest of rural-to-urban migrants themselves. Decentralization of entitlements for migrants is in service of other state goals and priorities around economic development, modernization, and increasing domestic consumer demand. The system, or more accurately various local subsystems, of urban benefits is not primarily about improving migrant welfare. The persistence of these institutions across administrations indicates that flexibility in whether and how to integrate migrant workers has endured for pragmatic reasons. Decentralization does not necessarily improve migrant welfare, but it is consistent with other state goals.
Some advantages of pliable citizenship make it practicable in the short term but may contain the seeds of their own demise. One major long-term downside is that it does not produce or maintain a healthy, stable labor force. Migrants who forego medical care or wait until they are severely ill to go to the emergency room or return home for treatment may suffer health consequences and be unable to continue working. Those families who are forced to enroll their children in makeshift private migrant schools will have a hard time attaining upward socioeconomic mobility. Another hazard is that migrant workers, who are relatively powerless as individuals vis-à-vis the state, can engage in collective action that disrupts a locality’s economy or social stability because of their sheer numbers. And pliable citizenship is costly to the state itself. Policies and practices that increase bureaucracy and shift over time require resources to create and sustain. Authorities have to design procedures such as residency points systems and eligibility rules for enrolling children in school, and their frontline counterparts then have to count and keep track of these methods and accompanying documentation. In the long run, pliable citizenship will not improve overall migrant welfare and poses risks for the state. In short, there has been more continuity than change.
Institutions of population management in China have been updated and repurposed, and these structures are deeply entrenched in social policy. Factors beyond the hukou system affect migrant rights, giving way to the emergence of new gradations of second-class citizenship. The state nudges migrants to do what the government prefers them to do while avoiding being held accountable. Cities keep a steady pool of labor to boost local economic development without having to provide the full set of rights, and officials delay deep, systemic reform that would improve migrant welfare. Migrant citizenship is malleable relative to that of other citizens, and this inequality benefits the state.
Notes
1. Alexsia T. Chan, Beyond Coercion: The Politics of Inequality in China (New York: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming).
2. See State Council, “Guojia xinxing chengzhen hua guihua (2014–2020)” (The National New-Type Urbanization Plan [2014–2020]), March 16, 2014, http://
www .gov .cn /zhengce /2014 -03 /16 /content _2640075 .htm. 3. State Council, “China Unveils Landmark Urbanization Plan,” August 23, 2014, http://
english .www .gov .cn /policies /policy _watch /2014 /08 /23 /content _281474983027472 .htm. 4. State Council, “China Unveils Landmark Urbanization Plan.”
5. This chapter examines migrants’ pliable citizenship across six cities in four regions, three sectors, and two types of services. The findings are based on fieldwork in Beijing, Chengdu, Shanghai, Guangzhou, Hangzhou, and Dongguan between 2010 and 2019. The focus is on large, top-tier municipalities rather than smaller cities, because many workers prefer more developed cities, where there are more job opportunities and higher wages. Social services are usually most contested in these desirable destinations, and this is consistent with the finding that more developed cities tend to impose higher barriers to entry for household registration. Interview with public policy scholar in Beijing, July 2017; Li Zhang and Li Tao, “Barriers to the Acquisition of Urban Hukou in Chinese Cities,” Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space 44, no. 12 (2012): 2883–900. In one survey, 70 percent of respondents willing to settle in cities hoped to put down roots in big cities. National Health and Family Planning Commission of China, “Summary of China’s Migrant Population Report for 2013,” May 16, 2014, http://
en .nhfpc .gov .cn /2014 -05 /16 /c _46667 .htm. Of the many public services, the chapter looks at health care and education, both crucial to human development and China’s long-term growth prospects and of key importance to migrant worker families. 6. This chapter focuses on the social rights of migrants, adopting a widely used framework for understanding and categorizing citizenship. See Thomas H. Marshall, “Citizenship and Social Class,” in The Welfare State Reader, ed. Christopher Pierson and Francis G. Castles (Malden, MA: Polity Press, 2006), 30–39.
7. Chan, Beyond Coercion.
8. Jeremy Wallace, Cities and Stability: Urbanization, Redistribution, and Regime Survival (New York: Oxford University Press, 2014).
9. C. Cindy Fan, “The Elite, the Natives, and the Outsiders: Migration and Labor Market Segmentation in Urban China,” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 92, no. 1 (2002): 103–24; Dorothy J. Solinger, Contesting Citizenship in Urban China: Peasant Migrants, the State, and the Logic of the Market (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1999); Fei-Ling Wang, Organizing through Division and Exclusion: China’s Hukou System (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2005); Martin King Whyte, ed., One Country, Two Societies: Rural-Urban Inequality in Contemporary China (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2010); Jieh-Min Wu, “Rural Migrants Workers and China’s Differential Citizenship: A Comparative Institutional Analysis,” in One Country, Two Societies: Rural-Urban Inequality in Contemporary China, ed. Martin King Whyte (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2010), 55–81; Kam Wing Chan, “The Chinese Hukou System at 50,” Eurasian Geography and Economics 50, no. 2 (2009): 197–221; Kam Wing Chan, Fang Cai, Guanghua Wan, and Man Wang, eds., Urbanization with Chinese Characteristics: The Hukou System and Migration (New York: Routledge, 2018); Kam Wing Chan and Li Zhang, “The Hukou System and Rural-Urban Migration in China: Processes and Changes,” China Quarterly, no. 160 (1999): 818–55; Kam Wing Chan and Will Buckingham, “Is China Abolishing the Hukou System?,” China Quarterly, no. 195 (2008): 582–606; Tiejun Cheng and Mark Selden, “The Origins and Social Consequences of China’s Hukou System,” China Quarterly, no. 139 (1994): 644–68.
10. Jonathan Unger and Kaxton Siu, “Chinese Migrant Factory Workers across Four Decades: Shifts in Work Conditions, Urbanization, and Family Strategies,” Labor History 60, no. 6 (2019): 765–78.
11. Chan and Buckingham, “Is China Abolishing the Hukou System?”; Zhonghua Guo and Tuo Liang, “Differentiating Citizenship in Urban China: A Case Study of Dongguan City,” Citizenship Studies 21, no. 7 (2017): 773–91.
12. Tao Liu and Qiujie Shi, “Acquiring a Beijing Hukou: Who Is Eligible and Who Is Successful?,” China Quarterly, no. 243 (2020): 855–68.
13. On the hukou system, see Kam Wing Chan, Cities with Invisible Walls: Reinterpreting Urbanization in Post-1949 China (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994); Chan, “The Chinese Hukou System at 50”; Chan and Buckingham, “Is China Abolishing the Hukou System?”; Chan and Zhang “The Hukou System and Rural-Urban Migration”; Fan, “The Elite, the Natives, and the Outsiders”; Solinger, Contesting Citizenship in Urban China.
14. For more on Xi’s power centralization and authoritarian consolidation, see Elizabeth Economy, The Third Revolution: Xi Jinping and the New Chinese State (New York: Oxford University Press, 2018); Carl Minzner, End of an Era: How China’s Authoritarian Revival Is Undermining Its Rise (New York: Oxford University Press, 2018).
15. Michael Lipsky, Street-Level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Services (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1980).
16. Susan H. Whiting, “The Cadre Evaluation System at the Grass Roots: The Paradox of Party Rule,” in Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era, ed. Barry Naughton and Dali Yang (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2004), 101–19; Kevin J. O’Brien and Lianjiang Li, “Selective Policy Implementation in Rural China,” Comparative Politics 31, no. 2 (1999): 167–86.
17. Maria Edin, “State Capacity and Local Agent Control in China: CCP Cadre Management from a Township Perspective,” China Quarterly, no. 173 (2003): 35–52.
18. Dali L. Yang, “China’s Looming Labor Shortage,” Far Eastern Economic Review 168, no. 2 (2005): 19–24.
19. Yuming Cui, Jingjing Meng, and Changrong Lu, “Recent Developments in China’s Labor Market: Labor Shortage, Rising Wages and Their Implications,” Review of Development Economics 22, no. 3 (2018): 1217–38.
20. Interview with factory-government liaison, Dongguan, December 2010.
21. Interviews with factory-government liaison, Dongguan, December 2010, and economics scholar, Guangzhou, January 2011.
22. The number is calculated from China Labour Bulletin, “Strike Map,” 2018, http://
maps .clb .org .hk /strikes /en. 23. China Labour Bulletin, “Strike Map.”
24. See “Guangzhou laodong zhengyi susong qingkuang baipishu (2014–2016)” (White paper on labor dispute litigation in Guangzhou [2014–2016]),Guangzhou Shenpan Wang, May 12, 2017, http://
www .gzcourt .gov .cn /upfile /File /201705 /12 /101657100 .pdf. 25. Manfred Elfstrom and Sarosh Kuruvilla, “The Changing Nature of Labor Unrest in China,” ILR Review 67, no. 2 (2014): 453–80.
26. Ngai Pun and Huilin Lu, “Unfinished Proletarianization: Self, Anger, and Class Action among the Second Generation of Peasant-Workers in Present-Day China,” Modern China 36, no. 5 (2010): 493–519.
27. Interviews with migrant workers, Beijing, December 2010, and nongovernmental organization (NGO) staff member, Chengdu, July 2012.
28. Interviews with migrant workers, Beijing, December 2010, and Chengdu, July 2012.
29. See, for example, Whyte, One Country, Two Societies; Yuen Yuen Ang, How China Escaped the Poverty Trap (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2016).
30. Li Keqiang, “Li Keqiang Expounds on Urbanization,” China.org.cn, May 26, 2013, http://
www .china .org .cn /china /2013 -05 /26 /content _28934485 .htm. 31. Li, “Li Keqiang Expounds on Urbanization.”
32. Li Keqiang, “Full Text of Premier Li Keqiang’s Speech at the Opening Ceremony of the Annual Meeting of the New Champions 2019,” State Council, July 4, 2019, http://
english .www .gov .cn /premier /speeches /2019 /07 /04 /content _281476747574784 .htm. 33. State Council, “Guojia xinxing chengzhen hua guihua.”
34. State Council, “Xi: Principal Contradiction Facing Chinese Society Has Evolved in New Era,” October 18, 2017, http://
english .www .gov .cn /news /top _news /2017 /10 /18 /content _281475912458156 .htm. 35. The State Council Information Office released a white paper titled “Development of China’s Public Health as an Essential Element of Human Rights” in 2017. For the text, see State Council Information Office, accessed 2019, https://
www .scio .gov .cn /32618 /Document /1565200 /1565200 .htm. 36. National Development and Reform Commission, “2019 nian xinxing chengzhen hua jianshe zhongdian renwu” (Key tasks of new-type urbanization construction in 2019), April 2019, http://
www .ndrc .gov .cn /zcfb /zcfbtz /201904 /W020190408339953053184 .pdf. 37. Li, “Li Keqiang Expounds on Urbanization.”
38. “Beijing’s Point-Based Hukou System to Open for Annual Application,” Xinhua, May 17, 2019, http://
www .xinhuanet .com /english /2019 -05 /17 /c _138067093 .htm. 39. Interviews with social welfare scholar, Beijing, March 2012; former education official, Chengdu, May 2012; and NGO staff member, Shanghai, July 2017.
40. “China Urbanization Cost Could Top $106 Billion a Year: Think-Tank,” Reuters, July 30, 2013, https://
www .reuters .com /article /us -china -economy -urbanisation /china -urbanization -cost -could -top -106 -billion -a -year -think -tank -idUSBRE96T0JS20130730. 41. Alexsia T. Chan and Kevin J. O’Brien, “Phantom Services: Deflecting Migrant Workers in China,” China Journal, no. 81 (2019): 103–22.
42. People’s Republic of China Central People’s Government, “Beijing chengshi zongti guihua (2016 nian–2035 nian) fubu” (Beijing Municipal Master Plan [2016–2035] released), September 30, 2017, http://
www .gov .cn /xinwen /2017 -09 /30 /content _5228705 .htm; People’s Government of Beijing, “Report on the Work of the Government 2018 (Part 1),” March 27, 2018, http:// www .ebeijing .gov .cn /Government /reports /t1513295 .htm. 43. Cited in Huizhao Huang, Shulun Huang, and Qiuyu Ren, “Government Report Calls for Serious Reform of Residency System for Migrants,” Caixin, February 1, 2019, https://
www .caixinglobal .com /2019 -02 -01 /government -report -calls -for -serious -reform -of -residency -system -for -migrants -101377233 .html. 44. Huang, Huang, and Ren, “Government Report Calls for Serious Reform.”
45. Interviews with migrant workers, Beijing, December 2011.
46. Interview with school principal, Beijing, March 2012.
47. Interview with migrant worker, Guangzhou, July 2017.
48. Interview with NGO staff member, Shanghai, July 2017.
49. Interview with migrant worker, Shanghai, July 2017.
50. Interview with migrant worker, Beijing, December 2011.
51. Interviews with scholar-activist, Chengdu, May 2012, and school principal, Chengdu, May 2012.
52. Interviews with doctor, Guangzhou, July 2017, and scholar-activist, Chengdu, July 2017.
53. John Knight and Ramani Gunatilaka, “Rural-Urban Migration and Happiness in China,” in World Happiness Report 2018, ed. John F. Helliwell, Richard Layard, and Jeffrey D. Sachs (New York: Sustainable Development Solutions Network, 2018), 67–88.
54. Interview with migrant worker, Guangzhou, July 2017.